The Penn Effect is often analyzed through the lens of purchasing power parity (PPP), which is the theory that in the absence of transportation costs and other trade barriers, identical goods should have the same price when expressed in a common currency across different countries. However, the Penn Effect suggests that in reality, differences in income levels can lead to significant price variations. In wealthier countries, higher demand for services and goods, along with higher labor costs, leads to increased prices, especially for non-tradable services like housing, healthcare, and education.
One of the major implications of the Penn Effect is that it helps explain why GDP comparisons between countries may not always reflect true living standards. When calculating income levels or comparing economic development, traditional measures like GDP per capita often fail to account for the differences in price levels. As a result, a person in a richer country may have a higher nominal income, but their purchasing power may not be significantly higher than that of someone in a poorer country if adjusted for local price levels.
Moreover, the Penn Effect also influences international trade and investment decisions. For instance, firms may seek to locate in countries with lower price levels to reduce production costs, taking advantage of cheaper labor and resources while maintaining competitive pricing in global markets. Understanding the Penn Effect is crucial for policymakers and economists in making accurate assessments of economic conditions and designing effective economic strategies.